1The RAND Corporation,Santa Monica,California.
2Columbia University School of Nursing,New York,New York.
Infect Control Hosp Epidemiol. 2018 May;39(5):509-515. doi: 10.1017/ice.2018.18. Epub 2018 Feb 19.
OBJECTIVEThe financial incentives for hospitals to improve care may be weaker if higher insurer payments for adverse conditions offset a portion of hospital costs. The purpose of this study was to simulate incentives for reducing hospital-acquired infections under various payment configurations by Medicare, Medicaid, and private payers.DESIGNMatched case-control study.SETTINGA large, urban hospital system with 1 community hospital and 2 tertiary-care hospitals.PATIENTSAll patients discharged in 2013 and 2014.METHODSUsing electronic hospital records, we identified hospital-acquired bloodstream infections (BSIs) and urinary tract infections (UTIs) with a validated algorithm. We assessed excess hospital costs, length of stay, and payments due to infection, and we compared them to those of uninfected patients matched by propensity for infection.RESULTSIn most scenarios, hospitals recovered only a portion of excess HAI costs through increased payments. Patients with UTIs incurred incremental costs of $6,238 (P<.01), while payments increased $1,901 (P<.05) at public diagnosis-related group (DRG) rates. For BSIs, incremental costs were $15,367 (P<.01), while payments increased $7,895 (P<.01). If private payers reimbursed a 200% markup over Medicare DRG rates, hospitals recovered 55% of costs from BSI and UTI among private-pay patients and 54% for BSI and 33% for UTI, respectively, across all patients. Under per-diem payment for private patients with no markup, hospitals recovered 71% of excess costs of BSI and 88% for UTI. At 150% markup and per-diem payments, hospitals profited.CONCLUSIONSHospital incentives for investing in patient safety vary by payer and payment configuration. Higher payments provide resources to improve patient safety, but current payment structures may also reduce the willingness of hospitals to invest in patient safety.Infect Control Hosp Epidemiol 2018;39:509-515.
如果较高的保险公司对不利条件的支付抵消了医院成本的一部分,那么医院改善护理的经济激励可能会减弱。本研究的目的是通过医疗保险、医疗补助和私人支付者的各种支付配置来模拟降低医院获得性感染的激励措施。
匹配病例对照研究。
一家大型城市医院系统,包括 1 家社区医院和 2 家三级保健医院。
2013 年和 2014 年出院的所有患者。
使用电子医院记录,我们使用经过验证的算法确定医院获得性血流感染(BSI)和尿路感染(UTI)。我们评估了感染引起的超额医院费用、住院时间和支付金额,并将其与感染倾向性匹配的未感染患者进行比较。
在大多数情况下,医院通过增加支付仅收回了部分 HAI 成本。UTI 患者的增量成本为 6238 美元(P<.01),而公共诊断相关组(DRG)费率下的支付增加了 1901 美元(P<.05)。对于 BSI,增量成本为 15367 美元(P<.01),而支付增加了 7895 美元(P<.01)。如果私人支付者按照 Medicare DRG 费率的 200%进行报销,那么私人支付患者的 BSI 和 UTI 中,医院分别从私人支付患者中收回了 55%和 54%的成本,而所有患者的 BSI 和 UTI 分别收回了 55%和 33%。对于私人患者的按日计费且没有加价,医院收回了 BSI 过度费用的 71%和 UTI 的 88%。在加价 150%和按日计费的情况下,医院盈利。
医院在患者安全方面的投资激励因支付方和支付配置而异。更高的支付提供了改善患者安全的资源,但当前的支付结构也可能降低医院投资患者安全的意愿。
感染控制与医院流行病学 2018;39:509-515.